Discount rate policy under the Classical Gold Standard: Core versus periphery (1870s–1914)

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2012.12.003Get rights and content

Abstract

Drawing on a new data set of monthly observations, this paper investigates similarities and differences in the discount rate policy of 12 European countries under the Classical Gold Standard. It asks, in particular, whether the bank rate policy followed different patterns in core and peripheral countries. Based on OLS, ordered probit and pooled estimations of central bank discount rate behaviour, two main findings emerge: firstly, the discount rate decisions of core countries were motivated by a desire to keep the exchange-rate within the gold points. In stark contrast, the discount rate decisions of peripheral countries reflected changes in the domestic cover ratio. The main reason for the difference in behaviour was the limited effectiveness of the discount rate tool for peripheral countries, which resulted in more frequent gold point violations. Consequently, peripheral countries relied on high reserve levels and oriented their discount rate policy towards maintaining the reserve level. Secondly, interest rate decisions were influenced by Berlin and London to a similar degree, suggesting that the European branch of the Classical Gold Standard was less London-centred than had been hitherto assumed. In establishing general patterns of discount rate policy, this paper aims to contribute to the wider discussion on monetary policy under the gold standard and the core–periphery dichotomy.

Introduction

The Classical Gold Standard (1870s–1914) has attracted the interest of economists, economic historians and policy-makers ever since its foundation. The exchange-rate stability among most countries of the world for some forty years was unprecedented and remained an inspiration to policy-makers after both world wars. At the time, adherence to gold was not entirely uncontroversial, as the international bimetallic movement of the mid-1870s to mid-1890s demonstrates (Reti, 1998). However, the perspective soon changed as a result of monetary instability following World War I and high exchange-rate volatility in the 1930s. Policy-makers came to regard the pre-World War I gold standard as the benchmark against which any international monetary system should be measured — hence the label Classical Gold Standard.

Economists and economic historians, aware of the costs and benefits of adhering to a system of fixed exchange-rates, have tended to avoid the eulogistic tone of policy-makers. They have contributed to the gold standard myth, however, by producing a highly stereotypical account of its workings. Some of the stereotypes have surely been overturned by more recent research. Following Hume's price-specie mechanism (1752), the textbook account of the gold standard had it that gold was physically shipped between countries to settle balance-of-payments disequilibria. Recent research, following earlier leads (Lindert, 1969), has demonstrated the importance and sophistication of foreign exchange policy (Jobst, 2009). Other scholars have provided the empirical basis to verify or reject some of the claims made in the earlier gold standard literature, as in the discussion of the benefits of gold standard adherence which are seen in improved access to global capital markets and reduced transaction costs with other gold standard countries (Bordo and Rockoff, 1996, Lόpez-Cόrdova and Meissner, 2003). Yet another strand of the recent literature has highlighted conditions crucial to the workings of the Classical Gold Standard which had been neglected so far, such as the importance of labour mobility and remittances in smoothing the adjustment mechanism (Esteves and Khoudour-Castéras, 2009, Khoudour-Castéras, 2005).

While the gold standard myth has given way to a broader empirical analysis in some debates, in other areas it stubbornly persists. One of these areas is the alleged core–periphery dichotomy. It is argued that the adjustment process to balance-of-payments disequilibria was much smoother for the industrialised core countries of North-western Europe as opposed to the peripheral economies. Different factors have been emphasized in an effort to explain the alleged advantages of the core countries in the adjustment process. Drawing on the theory of optimum currency areas, one school of thought has argued that core countries were better suited to monetary integration (Martín Aceña and Reis, 2000). Others have argued that the central banks1 of core countries helped each other in times of crisis, but did not help peripheral economies for the lack of self-interest (Eichengreen, 19952). More recently, differences in credibility have been emphasized (Hallwood et al., 1996, Bordo and MacDonald, 2005), whereas an older school of thought highlighted the peripheral countries' role as debtors in the global financial system, which made them vulnerable to sudden withdrawals of funds in times of financial strain (de Cecco, 1974).

Although the existing literature alludes to the core–periphery dichotomy, it is surprising to see that little effort has gone into analysing what exactly these differences consist of. A number of publications in recent years on the experiences of individual countries have greatly expanded our knowledge of the European periphery under the Classical Gold Standard (Esteves et al., 2009, Jobst, 2009, Reis, 2007, Tattara, 2003, Ögren and Oksendal, 2012). However, case studies, by design, can never be a substitute for a cross-country study analysing the similarities and differences between countries based on the same methodology. Such comparative studies on different aspects of monetary policy under the Classical Gold Standard exist, but they are mostly confined to comparing core countries (Giovannini, 1986, Contamin and Denise, 1999).

This paper aims to provide the first systematic comparison of discount rate policy under the Classical Gold Standard based on the concept of a central bank reaction function. The discount rate was the most important monetary policy instrument at the time; Bagehot's famous description of the London money market, for instance, is almost exclusively concerned with the discount rate (Bagehot, 1878). Modern research, going back to Bloomfield's ground-breaking 1959 study (Bloomfield, 1959, p. 27), has followed this approach. Drawing on a sample of 12 European countries (Austria-Hungary, Belgium, Bulgaria, England, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Romania, Serbia, and Sweden) and relying on monthly data (the highest frequency available for all countries) we will analyse the determinants of discount rate policy; in particular, we will ask whether core and peripheral countries followed different patterns and, if so, explain why this was the case.

In the process of collecting the data required for this analysis, it became clear why a comparative study of similar size and data frequency had never been conducted before. With the exception of England, Italy and Norway, the central banks did not make their historical balance sheet data publicly available. Most of the data (though not all) could be found in the Annual Reports of the time, copies of which can nowadays only be found in the archives of the respective central banks. Hence intensive collaboration with the central banks' historical archives was needed to reconstruct the time series.3

Which countries do we view as core and which ones as periphery? This dichotomy is often used in the literature but rarely defined based on rigorous foundations. A classification based on GDP per capita appears problematic in this context, as some countries generally considered peripheral would need to be classified as core (Argentina comes to mind and Ford's famous comparison with the UK (Ford, 1962)). In our context, any definition should rather capture the position in the international economy and, in particular, the international financial system. Liquidity in the foreign exchange market, for instance, provides evidence of the ability to attract short-term capital. Another potential indicator might relate to the ability to attract long-term capital: raising long-term capital is more difficult for countries suffering from original sin than for those able to access global capital markets in domestic currency.

Classifying countries as core and periphery using these two or similar criteria might lead to conflicting results; the example of the US comes to mind, which Morgenstern and Schwartz classify as core, while Bordo and Eichengreen view it as peripheral in the pre-WW I financial architecture.4 Fortunately, our sample of 12 countries poses little risk of unclear classification. Based on an analysis of foreign exchange-market liquidity, Flandreau and Jobst (2005, p. 997) classify England, France, Germany, Belgium and the Netherlands as “key countries”5 of the international monetary system in 1880, a year which conveniently coincides with the beginning of our estimation period. We would choose the same five countries if we looked at the second criterion alluded to above, that is, the ability to issue sovereign bonds in terms of their own currency. From the 12 countries in our sample, Bordo and Flandreau (2003, p. 439) show that it is the same five countries which were in a position to issue debt abroad in their own currency. In the following, we will therefore categorise Belgium, England, France, Germany and the Netherlands as core countries and the other seven countries as periphery.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we will estimate central bank reaction functions for core and peripheral countries. Having established that the two types of countries reacted to different variables in setting their discount rate, Section 3 aims to explain the differences. Based on published sources and internal documents of the time, we will show that peripheral countries adapted the “English” gold standard to suit their needs; a modification which also impinged on how exactly the discount rate was to be used. Section 4 summarises and concludes.

Section snippets

Components of a central bank reaction function

Adherence to the gold standard implied two main constraints. First, in order to maintain confidence in the domestic monetary system, banks of note issue were required to hold a certain minimum level of reserves against bank notes in circulation. If the ratio between the two, usually referred to as the cover ratio, fell below some statutory level (typically 30%–40%), some sort of sanction would be applied. In extremis, this could lead to the complete loss of the note issuing privilege granted by

Central bank behaviour during the periods of global financial strain

As indicated earlier, there were three periods of sustained gold point violations by peripheral countries: the Boer War, starting in 1899; the crisis of 1907; and the Balkan Wars of 1912/13. We briefly explain each episode and then analyse the discount rate behaviour of core and peripheral countries during these crises. Subsequently, we will support our analysis of the data by a study of the internal protocols and the Annual Reports of the Austro-Hungarian bank.

  • (a)

    The Boer War began in October

Conclusion

In this paper we have provided the first systematic comparison of discount rate policy under the Classical Gold Standard based on the concept of a central bank reaction function. Drawing on a new data set of monthly observations for 12 European countries, we analysed the determinants of discount rate policy; in particular, we asked whether core and peripheral countries followed different patterns and why this was the case.

Two key findings emerged: firstly, core and periphery differed in the

Acknowledgment

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the AEA, EHES, EHS and IEHA meetings; at seminars in Antwerp, Berkeley, Glasgow, Leuven, Moscow (ICEF), NYU, Oxford, Paris, Rutgers, York; and at the EABH Young Scholars Workshop in Rotterdam and the SEEMHN Annual Conference in Bucharest. I am grateful to all participants for their spirited discussion and helpful suggestions, and in particular to Dion Bongaerts, Michael Bordo, Carsten Burhop, Barry Eichengreen, Sergey Gelman, Clemens Jobst, Joost

References (57)

  • E. Canjels et al.

    Measuring market integration: foreign exchange-arbitrage and the gold standard, 1879–1913

    The Review of Economics and Statistics

    (2004)
  • F. Capie

    Banking in Europe in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries: the role of the central bank

  • F.H. Capie et al.

    A Monetary History of the United Kingdom. 1870–1982. Volume 1. Data, Sources, and Methods

    (1995)
  • R. Contamin

    Interdépendences financières et dilemma de politique monétaire: la Banque de France entre 1880 et 1913

    Revue Economique

    (2003)
  • R. Contamin et al.

    Quelle autonomie pour les politiques monétaires sous l'étalon-or, 1880–1913?

  • N. Davutyan et al.

    The operations of the Bank of England, 1890–1908: a dynamic probit approach

    Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking

    (1995)
  • M. de Cecco

    Money and Empire: the International Gold Standard, 1890–1914

    (1974)
  • A.M. de Jong

    Geschiedenes van de Nederlandsche Bank

    (1967)
  • R. de Mattia

    I bilanci degli istituti di emissione italiani dal 1845 al 1936, altre serie storiche di interesse monetario e fonti

  • M.A. Denzel

    The European Bill of Exchange. Its development from the Middle Ages to 1914

  • J. Dutton

    The Bank of England and the rules of the game under the international gold standard: new evidence

  • B. Eichengreen

    Central bank cooperation and exchange rate commitments: the classical and interwar gold standards compared

    Financial History Review

    (1995)
  • B. Eichengreen et al.

    Bank rate policy under the interwar gold standard: a dynamic probit model

    The Economic Journal

    (1985)
  • R. Esteves et al.

    A fantastic rain of gold: European migrants' remittances and balance of payments adjustment during the gold standard period

    Journal of Economic History

    (2009)
  • M. Flandreau

    Central bank cooperation in historical perspective: a sceptical view

    The Economic History Review

    (1998)
  • M. Flandreau et al.

    The ties that divide: a network analysis of the international monetary system, 1890–1910

    Journal of Economic History

    (2005)
  • A.G. Ford

    Britain and Argentina

    (1962)
  • M. Fratianni et al.

    Storia Monetaria d'Italia. Lira e politica monetaria dall'Unità all'Unione Europea

    (2001)
  • Cited by (23)

    • Democratic constraints and adherence to the classical gold standard

      2022, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      This suggests that the democratic constraints that we are highlighting were particularly important for peripheral countries for which commitment to the gold standard was not as firm as for core countries. This result is in line with the findings of Morys (2013) and Mitchener and Weidenmier (2015) regarding differences in the operation of the gold standard between the core and the periphery. In column 5 we proceed to exclude from our sample the countries that there were part of a monetary union when joining the gold standard.

    • Did monetary policy matter? Narrative evidence from the classical gold standard

      2018, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      As discussed above, the targets at the time related to convertibility and the main instrument was Bank Rate. There is also a long literature that suggests it is appropriate to model the Bank’s behaviour in this way (Davutyan and Parke, 1995; Dutton, 1984; Giovannini, 1986; Morys, 2013; Pippenger, 1984). Second, are the right variables included in the reaction function?

    • International shocks and the balance sheet of the Bank of France under the classical gold standard

      2016, Explorations in Economic History
      Citation Excerpt :

      Looking at the transcripts of BdF policy decisions available in the archives, we show that these interest rate changes required the presence of additional factors, especially undue pressure on the gold stock and on the exchange rate. Previous studies of French central banking based on OLS estimations found that neither exchange rate deviations (Gallarotti, 1995; Morys, 2013) nor the level of the liquidity ratio (Tullio and Wolters, 2003) affected the discount rate. Not surprisingly, these studies concluded that standard reaction functions explain little of the variation of the French discount rate compared to other countries (Gallarotti, 1995; Contamin and Denise, 1999).

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    I owe a special thanks to the following people for helping me collect the data: Kath Begley (Bank of England), Sofia Lazaretou (Bank of Greece), Alfredo Gigliobianco (Bank of Italy), Kalina Dimitrova (Bulgarian National Bank), Ms Beex (De Nederlandsche Bank), Ivo Maes and Arnold de Schepper (National Bank of Belgium), Virgiliu Stoenescu, Elisabeta Blejan, Brandusa Costache and Adriana Aloman (National Bank of Romania), Milan Sojic and Ljiljana Djurdjevic (National Bank of Serbia), Walter Antonowicz, Clemens Jobst, Bernhard Mussak and Thomas Scheiber (Österreichische Nationalbank), Erik Buyst, Martin Ivanov, Jan Tore Klovland, Larry Neal, Giuseppe Tattara, Anders Ögren, Lars Fredrik Oksendal and Marc Weidenmier.

    View full text